PreventionWeb.net
Global Assessment Report on Disaster Risk Reduction 2011
Revealing Risk, Redefining Development
  Previous  pageNext page 
 

5.3 Tailoring DRM strategies

Governments will need a range of different DRM strategies to address the different risk strata. It may be more cost-effective to reduce the more extensive risks using a mix of prospective and corrective risk management strategies. For some of the more intensive risks, corrective disaster risk management will not be cost-effective, although compensatory risk management could address them through insurance, reinsurance, transfer to capital markets, and contingent financing.

5.3.1 Identifying risk strata

Governments typically have three strategic DRM instruments at their disposal: prospective, corrective and compensatory.9  The portfolio of resources and their financial costs are very different for each. By assessing the full spectrum of risks they face, governments will be able to identify the most appropriate and cost-effective DRM strategies for each risk strata. Applying probabilistic risk modelling and cost–benefit analysis to develop a composite profile for each country can assist in defining a pragmatic mix of instruments depending on the economic and development status of a country.

From a risk-financing perspective, there are three possible strategies that a government can adopt to manage disaster risk: retaining the risk, insuring the risk and transferring the risk to capital markets.10  The decision how much risk to retain and how much to transfer is ultimately a government policy decision, based on considerations such as the value of the annual average and probable maximum loss, the fiscal space or capacity to invest in risk reduction, social and political acceptance of risk, and access to risk financing.

In general, it is more cost effective for governments to retain rather than insure extensive risks below the level of retention (Figure 5.6). From an insurance perspective, this stratum would normally be considered as a deductible, which governments would have to cover from their own resources.11 

Figure 5.6
Cost of different risk financing strategies within the different strata of disaster risk
Figure 5.6
It is more cost effective for a government to transfer intensive risks, between the deductible amount and the risk transfer limit, through insurance, reinsurance and through contingent credit and similar instruments, rather than to retain them. Beyond the risk transfer limit, risks cannot be insured, and can only be transferred to capital markets through instruments such as Cat Bonds, or are residual. Beyond this point, countries are likely to face the range of very low-probability emerging risks as described in Chapter 2.

In Colombia, for example, national insurance regulators have established that all insurers should have reserves, including reinsurance, to cover the probable maximum loss associated with a return period of 1500 years. This would be the risk transfer limit if the insurer decides to establish an excess loss threshold at that level, above which losses are not insured: a probable maximum loss of US$7.6 billion in the case of Colombia (Figure 5.7). If the deductible was established at 1 percent, the government would have to retain probable maximum losses of up to US$1.5 billion and cover annual average losses of approximately US$200 million with its own resources, below the level of retention.




A loss exceedance rate of 10 means it is likely that the associated loss will be exceeded 10 times a year in events with a return period of 0.1 years (1.2 months).
Figure 5.7
Hybrid loss exceedance curve for Colombia locating the deductible amount and risk transfer limit
Figure 5.7
Similar findings are seen in cost–benefit analyses of different climate adaptation options (ECA, 2009

x

ECA (Economics of Climate Adaptation). 2009. Shaping climate adaptation: A framework for decision-making. New York, USA: McKinsey & Company.
Available at http://www.mckinsey.com/App_Media/Images/Page_Images/Offices/SocialSector/PDF/ECA_Shaping_Climate%20Resilent_Development.pdf.
). Studies in 15 diverse countries including China, India, Mali, the United Kingdom, the United States of America and seven Caribbean countries showed that countries with a balanced portfolio of prospective, corrective and compensatory risk management measures were best positioned to proactively manage the total spectrum of climate risk.

5.3.2 Compensatory DRM

Many low- and middle-income countries are vulnerable to post-disaster resource deficits. In such circumstances governments have to divert funds from already tight budgets, re-allocate development loans to relief, and/or take on new loans from other states and the international community. Unless special conditions are granted, these sources of post-disaster finance are often slow and too expensive. When governments are unable to mobilize timely resources for recovery and reconstruction, the direct costs and impacts of the disaster can cascade into a range of other negative social and economic outcomes (GAR 11 paperSuarez and Linnerooth-Bayer, 2011

x

GAR11 Suarez, P. and Linnerooth-Bayer, J. 2011. Insurance-related instruments for disaster risk reduction. Background Paper prepared for the  2011 Global Assessment Report on Disaster Risk Reduction. Geneva, Switzerland: UNISDR.

Click here to view this GAR paper.
). For example, Honduras experienced a severe delay in economic growth due to difficulties repairing public infrastructure and assisting private sector recovery after the devastation of Hurricane Mitch in 1998. Five years after Mitch, its GDP was still 6 percent below pre-disaster projections (Mechler, 2004

x

Mechler, R. 2004. Natural disaster risk management and financing disaster losses in developing countries. Karlsruhe, Germany: Verlag für Versicherungswirtschaft.
.
).

Following intensive disasters, a lack of financial liquidity often leads to serious delays in recovery. In Haiti, of the almost US$6 billion pledged for the first two years after the January 2010 earthquake, only about US$0.5 billion or less than 10 percent had been transferred as of August 2010 (Ferris, 2010

x

Ferris, E. 2010. Earthquake and floods. Comparing Haiti and Pakistan. Washington DC, USA: The Brookings Institution.
Available at http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/Files/rc/papers/2010/0826_earthquakes_floods_ferris/0826_earthquakes_floods_ferris.pdf.
). This financing gap occurs after most major disasters and severely affects not only recovery itself, but also future investments in DRM.

Figure 5.8
Post-disaster funding process for intensive disaster events
Figure 5.1
   (Source: Adapted from Ghesquiere and Mahul, 2010

x

Ghesquiere, F. and Mahul, O. 2010. Financial protection of the state against natural disasters. A primer. Policy Research Working Paper 5429. Washington DC, USA: The World Bank.
.
)
Figure 5.8 shows the relative costs of relief, recovery and reconstruction, the three phases of post-disaster funding in the case of intensive disasters. Whereas the humanitarian community and the media tend to focus on relief, most postdisaster funding requirements are normally for reconstruction. In the case of extensive disasters, the amplitude of the curves may be inverted. Although governments may spend on relief (and to a lesser extent on recovery), the large initial costs of relief, and even of subsequent reconstruction, are usually absorbed by lowincome households and communities.

The cost of financial instruments that could address the needs of each of the funding phases varies considerably (Ghesquiere and Mahul, 2010

x

Ghesquiere, F. and Mahul, O. 2010. Financial protection of the state against natural disasters. A primer. Policy Research Working Paper 5429. Washington DC, USA: The World Bank.
.
). A government’s own contingency funds and grant financing from donors will always be the cheapest source of funding, but they have limitations in terms of quantity, predictability, speed of disbursement, and hidden costs, for example when funds are diverted from previously allocated development budgets and grants (Mahul and Skees, 2006

x

Mahul, O. and Skees, J. 2006. Piloting index-based livestock insurance in Mongolia. Washington DC, USA: The World Bank.
.
; Ghesquiere and Mahul, 2010

x

Ghesquiere, F. and Mahul, O. 2010. Financial protection of the state against natural disasters. A primer. Policy Research Working Paper 5429. Washington DC, USA: The World Bank.
.
). As highlighted by Box 5.4, contingency funds rarely provide more than a fraction of the funds required, and they may be exhausted by the cost of extensive disasters. The implication is that countries have to divert development resources to cover recovery and reconstruction costs, or transfer losses and impacts to affected households and communities. In both cases, the development deficit increases.

Box 5.4 Mexico’s disaster contingency fund


In 2010, Mexico’s disaster contingency fund (FONDEN) ran out of money. With an annual budget of 7 billion pesos, FONDEN had already spent 12 billion pesos by September and it estimated that it needed 25 billion by the end of the year due to non-assessed losses.12  FONDEN should have been in a better position given that Mexico issued a catastrophe bond for earthquakes and hurricanes, but extensive disasters, such as recurring floods and mudslides, led to FONDEN’s multi-billion pesos bill (rather than high-intensity hurricanes which could trigger the bond’s payouts). To make up the shortfall other government revenues had to be diverted.


Insurance and risk-sharing approaches can enable governments to complement other risk management strategies. They do this by ensuring or accelerating financing for relief, recovery and reconstruction, while at the same time guiding investment decisions that also contribute to reduce risks (GAR 11 paperSuarez and Linnerooth-Bayer, 2011

x

GAR11 Suarez, P. and Linnerooth-Bayer, J. 2011. Insurance-related instruments for disaster risk reduction. Background Paper prepared for the  2011 Global Assessment Report on Disaster Risk Reduction. Geneva, Switzerland: UNISDR.

Click here to view this GAR paper.
).

Two factors contribute to the cost of risk transfer: the entry level of risk transfer where the deductible amount is fixed, and the value of risk to be transferred between the deductible amount and the risk transfer limit. The cost of risk transfer can be significantly reduced if governments decide to retain and reduce part of their risk. For example, the cost of risk transfer with a deductible of 1 percent could be only a tenth of the cost of the transfer were no deductible established (GAR 11 paperERN-AL, 2011

x

GAR11 ERN-AL, 2011. Probabilistic modelling of disaster risk at global level: Development of a methodology and implementation of case studies. Phase 1A: Colombia, Mexico, Nepal. Background Paper prepared for the 2011 Global Assessment Report on Disaster Risk Reduction. Prepared by the Consortium Evaluación de Riesgos Naturales – América Latina. Geneva, Switzerland: UNISDR.

Click here to view this GAR paper.
).13  In the example of Colombia, using the hybrid curve, the cost of insuring the catastrophic risk between a level of retention of US$1.5 billion and a limit of risk transfer of US$7.6 billion would be calculated at approximately US$30–40 million per year.

New and innovative market-based instruments that promote DRM (Cardona, 2009

x

Cardona, O.D. 2009. La gestión financiera del riesgo de desastres: Instrumentos financieros de retención y transferencia para la comunidad andina. Lima, Peru: PREDECAN, Comunidad Andina.
.
; Hess and Hazell, 2009

x

Hess, U. and Hazell, P. 2009. Innovations in insuring the poor. Sustainability and scalability of index-based insurance for agriculture and rural livelihoods. IFPRI Policy Brief Focus 17 (Brief 5, December). Washington DC, USA: International Food Policy Research Institute.
.
) are now being developed and piloted throughout the world. In Peru for example, new contingent insurance policies are being developed that ensure payouts a month ahead of forecasted floods resulting from an El Niño event (Box 5.5). These instruments have been developed for individual micro-insurance schemes, but this is one of the first attempts to apply them to a government client. In Manizales, Colombia, an innovative collective insurance policy protects both public and private assets by cross-subsidising coverage for low-income groups from voluntary payments. Using the kind of sophisticated catastrophic risk models presented above enabled the municipal government to design a collective risk transfer instrument and promote an insurance culture in the city (Marulanda et al., 2010

x

Marulanda, M.C., Barbat, A. H., Cardona, O.D., and M. G. Mora. 2010. Design and implementation of seismic risk insurance to cover low-income homeowners by a cross-subsidy strategy. In: the 14th European Conference on Earthquake Engineering, 30 August – 3 September 2010. Ohrid, Republic of Macedonia: Macedonian Association for Earthquake Engineering (MAEE).
.
).

Box 5.5 Contingent insurance in Peru to reduce losses associated with El Niño forecasts


In Peru’s northern coastal region of Piura, seasons with extreme rainfall are often associated with El Niño-Southern Oscillation (ENSO) events, characterized by a warming of the tropical Pacific Ocean that can be observed and measured with a lead time of months.

Local, regional and national governments, and private stakeholders are cooperating to develop a financial instrument that triggers a payment when an ENSO event is predicted. This means that payments can be received before an event occurs so that the insured entity, usually local or sub-national governments, can mitigate losses that would likely occur in the absence of the insurance policy.

This type of insurance is potentially useful for three reasons: the payout takes place before the event, enabling protective and proactive measures to mitigate loss; the premium is not directly tied to the value of the asset protected; and the payout is dependent on the premium rather than estimated losses. The idea is that the insurance is taken out according to estimates of what needs to be invested to protect a certain asset, rather than replace (or repair) it, although accurately pricing the premium would depend on estimates of risks and of the costs of protection.

The most significant progress is a request in the Piura Regional Government budget to purchase the El Niño insurance in January 2011 to protect against the possibility of catastrophic flooding that could begin in early 2012 with a severe ENSO event. This project has led to new thinking and opportunities regarding the potential for ‘forecast index insurance’, in particular regarding ENSO events, which can affect seasonal patterns of rainfall, temperature and cause tropical cyclones in parts of Africa, Asia/ Pacific and the Americas.

(Source: Skees, 2010

x

Skees, J-R. 2010. Incorporating weather index insurance with territorial approaches to climate change (TACC) in northern Perú. Progress report developing el niño insurance for government stakeholders in Piura. Lexington, USA: GlobalAgRisk, Inc.
.
)

By ‘pricing’ not only risk, but also the benefits of risk reduction, insurance instruments provide incentives for DRM. With such contingent insurance policies, a government could, for example, calculate the expected costs of risk reduction for a specific hazard, estimate unavoidable losses and then decide on the premium it can pay.

Other market-based instruments provide built-in incentives and an appropriate pricing of premiums according to previous risk reducing investments (Box 5.6). Whereas these are mostly designed for individual and business customers, the incentive and pricing principles can also be adopted for macro-level schemes.

Box 5.6 Incentives for disaster risk reduction through new risk financing instruments


Examples of new approaches and instruments in the insurance sector reflect a growing concern for creating incentives to reduce disaster risk. A pilot insurance project in Ethiopia supported by the World Food Programme was designed to pay claims to the government based on a drought index, in the time window between observed lack of rain and actual materialization of losses. This allows stakeholders to address threats to food security in ways that prevent the depletion of farmers’ productive assets. This reduces future demand for humanitarian aid by enabling households to produce more food during subsequent seasons.

Governments that join regional risk pools can negotiate lower-cost insurance contracts, as they require the implementation of risk reduction measures for pool eligibility. The Africa Risk Capacity (ARC), for example, aims to provide African governments with financial weather risk management tools and funds to manage extreme events, while creating incentives for disaster risk reduction, planning and response. It intends to do this through a regional contingency funding mechanism for planned responses to weather emergencies and the establishment of an Africa-owned risk pooling entity.

With small economies and high debt levels, Caribbean states are highly dependent on unpredictable donor support to finance post-disaster needs. The Caribbean Catastrophe Risk Insurance Facility (CCRIF), set up in 2007, is a parametric risk transfer scheme owned by 16 countries, which provides short-term liquidity in the event of hurricanes and earthquakes. After the magnitude 7.4 earthquake that shook the eastern Caribbean in late 2007, the Saint Lucian and Dominican governments received CCRIF’s first payouts; a total of US$0.9 billion to finance urgent post-earthquake recovery efforts. In early 2010 when Haiti was struck by a massive earthquake, the government received the full policy amount of only US$8 million, highlighting both the advantages as well as the inherent limitations of the instrument when governments are severely underinsured.

Catastrophe bonds, such as the recent issue in Mexico, have not yet been linked directly to disaster risk reduction. Indirectly, however, the Mexican bond will provide immediate and reliable post-disaster payments to the government, though as highlighted in Box 5.4, it has clear limitations. Though it is a novel idea, a more direct link might be possible if instruments are designed to fund the incremental costs of adding risk reduction measures to reconstruction efforts.

(Source: GAR 11 paperSuarez and Linnerooth-Bayer, 2011

x

GAR11 Suarez, P. and Linnerooth-Bayer, J. 2011. Insurance-related instruments for disaster risk reduction. Background Paper prepared for the  2011 Global Assessment Report on Disaster Risk Reduction. Geneva, Switzerland: UNISDR.

Click here to view this GAR paper.
)

The prohibitive cost of some insurance and risk financing instruments means that a conservative fiscal policy and the use of contingency funds and contingent lines of credit from development banks may be the most efficient way to deal with intensive risks (Ghesquiere and Mahul, 2010). Insuring a large part of the potential loss is equivalent to multiplying the loss, considering that insurance always costs more than potential loss. The fact that in 2011, only 5 out of 82 countries reporting to HFA on disaster financing mechanisms have issued catastrophe bonds (whereas 41 rely on national contingency funds) is reflective of this.

Unlike insurance and catastrophe bonds, contingent credit ensures access to loans in times of crisis, a safe option for governments with limited post-disaster financing choices. This was the case in Mongolia where, by accessing contingent credit, the government secured liquidity in the aftermath of severe winter storms to provide relief and as a re-insurer to its livestock insurance programme (Box 5.7).

Box 5.7 Financing Mongolian index-based livestock insurance through distributing risk layers


In 2006, an index-based livestock insurance (IBLI) programme was introduced on a pilot basis in three Mongolian provinces. The insurance system was made affordable to herders and viable to insurers by a layered system of responsibility and payment. Herders retain small losses that do not affect the viability of their business. The next layer of losses is transferred to the private insurance industry through riskbased premium payments on the part of herders. A third layer of risk is absorbed by taxpayers, and the financing of the government’s potential losses during the pilot phase relies on a combination of reserves and, as a fourth layer, a contingent credit is provided by the World Bank and international reinsurance.

(Source: GAR 11 paperSuarez and Linnerooth-Bayer, 2011

x

GAR11 Suarez, P. and Linnerooth-Bayer, J. 2011. Insurance-related instruments for disaster risk reduction. Background Paper prepared for the  2011 Global Assessment Report on Disaster Risk Reduction. Geneva, Switzerland: UNISDR.

Click here to view this GAR paper.
, citing Mahul and Skees, 2006

x

Mahul, O. and Skees, J. 2006. Piloting index-based livestock insurance in Mongolia. Washington DC, USA: The World Bank.
.
)

Importantly, contingent credit can be linked to DRM as shown by the World Bank’s CAT Deferred Drawdown Option, which requires eligible countries to have a DRM programme in place. The loan may be ‘drawn down’ after a disaster, unless the government has received prior notification that their DRM programme is not being implemented in accordance with the agreement. The fact that the lines of credit are contingent on the development of DRM strategies means that Ministries of Finance get directly involved in a dialogue on risk reduction.

Different country contexts create different distributions of risk strata, and correspondingly, different ‘optimal’ portfolios of prospective, corrective and compensatory risk management. For example, in countries with high levels of drought risk and large agricultural economies, such as China, India or Mali, prospective and corrective risk management measures such as irrigation control, improved soil management and improved fertilizer use are less expensive than risk transfer. In the case of small island states threatened by rising sea levels, such as Samoa, relatively low-cost measures such as planting mangroves and using mobile flood barriers are more cost-effective than building sea walls, but risk transfer is the most efficient solution (ECA, 2009

x

ECA (Economics of Climate Adaptation). 2009. Shaping climate adaptation: A framework for decision-making. New York, USA: McKinsey & Company.
Available at http://www.mckinsey.com/App_Media/Images/Page_Images/Offices/SocialSector/PDF/ECA_Shaping_Climate%20Resilent_Development.pdf.
).



Notes

9 See Preface and Chapter 1 for definitions of these strategies.

10 Insurance is a form of risk transfer, but insurance and reinsurance companies, as well as countries, increasingly transfer their risk to capital and derivatives markets to cover major losses through alternative risk transfer (ART) instruments such as Catastrophe Bonds.

11 In insurance terminology, the deductible is the part of the claim that is not covered by the insurance company and that will have to be borne by the insured party. nonetheless, each small event (extensive risk) usually incurs losses lower than the deductible, and therefore, is not covered by the insurance but instead needs to be covered by the government.

12 See www.artemis.bm/blog/2010/09/16/fondenmexicos- disaster-fund-exceeds-its-annual-budget/ and Ruben Hofliger, Ministry of the Interior of Mexico, UN General Assembly Informal Debate on Disaster Risk Reduction, 9 February 2011, New York, USA.

13 The costs of transferring risks of a specific layer can be calculated from the expected annual loss, incorporating the expected loss and the probability of occurrence by event (the technical estimation of basic risk premium). This means that the higher the deductible amount (i.e., the more the cost of the risk is retained by the premium holder), the lower the premium or the cost of insurance (see GAR 11 paperERN-AL, 2011

x

GAR11 ERN-AL, 2011. Probabilistic modelling of disaster risk at global level: Development of a methodology and implementation of case studies. Phase 1A: Colombia, Mexico, Nepal. Background Paper prepared for the 2011 Global Assessment Report on Disaster Risk Reduction. Prepared by the Consortium Evaluación de Riesgos Naturales – América Latina. Geneva, Switzerland: UNISDR.

Click here to view this GAR paper.
, Chapter 7, Tables 7.1 and 7.2). This level of retention is established depending on the solvency and financial convenience of the party or government. In addition, investing in DRR (e.g. reducing the level of exposure and vulnerability through retrofitting) has direct implications for the calculation of the premium. If the amount and frequency of expected losses is reduced, this will lower the premium for catastrophe insurance cover or other risk transfer solutions.

GAR 11 Background documents
  x 
Close!

GAR11GAR 2011 Contributing Papers

ERN-AL. 2010. Seismic risk assessment of schools in the Andean region in South America and Central America. Bogotá, Colombia, Barcelona, Spain, and México DF: Consortium Evaluación de Riesgos Naturales – América Latina. [View]

ERN-AL, 2011. Probabilistic modelling of disaster risk at global level: Development of a methodology and implementation of case studies. Phase 1A: Colombia, Mexico, Nepal. Prepared by the Consortium Evaluación de Riesgos Naturales – América Latina. [View]

Ievers, J. and Bhatia, S. 2011. Recovery as a catalyst for reducing risk. IRP. [View]

Karayalcin, C. and Thompson, P. 2010. Decision-making constraints on the implementation of viable disaster risk reduction projects. Some perspectives from economics. . [View]

Llosa, S. and Zodrow, I. 2011. Disaster risk reduction legislation as a basis for effective adaptation. [>View]

Moreno, A. and Cardona, O.D. 2011. Efectos de los desastres naturales sobre el crecimiento, el desempleo, la inflación y la distribución del ingreso: Una evaluación de los casos de Colombia y México. [View]

Okazaki, K. 2010. Incentives for safer buildings. lessons from Japan. [View]

Rogers, D. Tsirkunov, V. 2011. The costs and benefits of early warning systems. [View]

Scott, Z. and Tarazona, M. 2011. Decentralization and disaster risk reduction. Study on disaster risk reduction, decentralization and political economy analysis for UNDP contribution to the GAR11. [View]

Suarez, P. and Linnerooth-Bayer, J. 2011. Insurance-related instruments for disaster risk reduction. . [View]

Williams, G. 2011. The political economy of disaster risk reduction. Study on Disaster Risk Reduction, Decentralization and Political Economy Analysis for UNDP contribution to the GAR11. [View]
  Previous  pageNext page 
Contact us  |  Disclaimer  |  Our Sponsors  |  References  |  Acknowledgements  |  PreventionWeb |  The Global Platform  |  © United Nations 2011.